Timothy T. Taylor Home Page
Resume
Journal of Economic Perspectives
Articles and Writing
Economics Textbook
Classroom Teaching
The Teaching Company
High School Pedagogy
Editing
Family
Contact

Articles and Writing

May 12, 1996
"A World View of Minimum Wage"
San Jose Mercury News
By Timothy Taylor
<< Back to 1996 menu

FOR straight talk on the issue of raising the minimum wage, detached from election year shenanigans, take a small step backward in time, and a large step sideways to an international perspective.

In 1994 and 1995, the Paris-based Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, an international body whose member-nations represent the world's developed economies, published a study in several volumes examining why unemployment in much of Europe has been been stuck in at double-digit rates over the last two decades. Unemployment rates for European youth have been even higher, commonly exceeding 20 percent.

There are many reasons, of course, including generous levels of government benefits in Europe that give workers less incentive to take a low-paying job, government requirements of employers that raise the cost of hiring, and so on. Another factor, at least in some countries, is a high minimum wage.

If the minimum wage is at or above half of the average wage, as it was in France, the Netherlands, and New Zealand in the late 1980s - and in the United States in the 1950s and 1960s - then it has a fairly strong ''bite,'' as the OECD puts it, in reducing employment.

But if the minimum wage is only one-third of the average wage, as is presently the case in Canada, Spain, and the United States, then its bite is smaller. Even if the U.S. minimum wage rises from $4.25 to $5.15, it would only be about 40 percent of the average wage.

"Increasing the minimum wage from a high level relative to average wages may prompt large cuts in employment," as the OECD puts it, "whereas the unemployment consequences may be small when the minimum wage is already low."

Some studies of minimum wages predict that they cost no jobs at all. Other studies in France, Canada, and the United States imply that raising the U.S. minimum to $5.15 would cost perhaps 200,000 jobs.

There are moderate arguments to support a slightly higher minimum wage. Even if it does cost a month's worth of job growth, perhaps this price is worth paying if it means a higher incentive for jobless people to go to work.

But other benefits of a higher minimum wage are oversold. For someone who supports a family by working at the minimum wage, a higher wage (assuming they don't lose their job) will mean lower eligibility for welfare, food stamps, Medicaid, and the earned income tax credit, which is available only to low-wage workers with children. After these adjustments, their standard of living will barely budge.

It's pleasant to pretend that we live in the Land of Milk and Honey, where government can solve social problems by passing laws with no adverse consequences and zero public cost.

But back here in Reality-ville, if we want to raise the take-home pay of low-wage workers immediately without endangering their jobs, the obvious policy tools are to reduce their income or Social Security and Medicare taxes, or to raise the earned income tax credit. If we must raise the minimum wage, then it would be wise to have several tiers, as the OECD suggests, with lower levels for teen-agers and low-wage geographic areas.

<< Back to 1996 menu